1. Po raz pierwszy odwiedzasz EDU. LEARN

    Odwiedzasz EDU.LEARN

    Najlepszym sposobem na naukę języka jest jego używanie. W EDU.LEARN znajdziesz interesujące teksty i videa, które dadzą Ci taką właśnie możliwość. Nie przejmuj się - nasze filmiki mają napisy, dzięki którym lepiej je zrozumiesz. Dodatkowo, po kliknięciu na każde słówko, otrzymasz jego tłumaczenie oraz prawidłową wymowę.

    Nie, dziękuję
  2. Mini lekcje

    Podczas nauki języka bardzo ważny jest kontekst. Zdjęcia, przykłady użycia, dialogi, nagrania dźwiękowe - wszystko to pomaga Ci zrozumieć i zapamiętać nowe słowa i wyrażenia. Dlatego stworzyliśmy Mini lekcje. Są to krótkie lekcje, zawierające kontekstowe slajdy, które zwiększą efektywność Twojej nauki. Są cztery typy Mini lekcji - Gramatyka, Dialogi, Słówka i Obrazki.

    Dalej
  3. Wideo

    Ćwicz język obcy oglądając ciekawe filmiki. Wybierz temat, który Cię interesuje oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknij na filmik. Nie martw się, obok każdego z nich są napisy. A może wcale nie będą Ci one potrzebne? Spróbuj!

    Dalej
  4. Teksty

    Czytaj ciekawe artykuły, z których nauczysz się nowych słówek i dowiesz więcej o rzeczach, które Cię interesują. Podobnie jak z filmikami, możesz wybrać temat oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknąć na wybrany artykuł. Nasz interaktywny słownik pomoże Ci zrozumieć nawet trudne teksty, a kontekst ułatwi zapamiętanie słówek. Dodatkowo, każdy artykuł może być przeczytany na głos przez wirtualnego lektora, dzięki czemu ćwiczysz słuchanie i wymowę!

    Dalej
  5. Słowa

    Tutaj możesz znaleźć swoją listę "Moje słówka", czyli funkcję wyszukiwania słówek - a wkrótce także słownik tematyczny. Do listy "Moje słówka" możesz dodawać słowa z sekcji Videa i Teksty. Każde z słówek dodanych do listy możesz powtórzyć później w jednym z naszych ćwiczeń. Dodatkowo, zawsze możesz iść do swojej listy i sprawdzić znaczenie, wymowę oraz użycie słówka w zdaniu. Użyj naszej wyszukiwarki słówek w części "Słownictwo", aby znaleźć słowa w naszej bazie.

    Dalej
  6. Lista tekstów

    Ta lista tekstów pojawia się po kliknięciu na "Teksty". Wybierz poziom trudności oraz temat, a następnie artykuł, który Cię interesuje. Kiedy już zostaniesz do niego przekierowany, kliknij na "Play", jeśli chcesz, aby został on odczytany przez wirtualnego lektora. W ten sposób ćwiczysz umiejętność słuchania. Niektóre z tekstów są szczególnie interesujące - mają one odznakę w prawym górnym rogu. Koniecznie je przeczytaj!

    Dalej
  7. Lista Video

    Ta lista filmików pojawia się po kliknięciu na "Video". Podobnie jak w przypadku Tekstów, najpierw wybierz temat, który Cię interesuje oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknij na wybrane video. Te z odznaką w prawym górnym rogu są szczególnie interesujące - nie przegap ich!

    Dalej
  8. Dziękujemy za skorzystanie z przewodnika!

    Teraz już znasz wszystkie funkcje EDU.LEARN! Przygotowaliśmy do Ciebie wiele artykułów, filmików oraz mini lekcji - na pewno znajdziesz coś, co Cię zainteresuje!

    Teraz zapraszamy Cię do zarejestrowania się i odkrycia wszystkich możliwości portalu.

    Dziękuję, wrócę później
  9. Lista Pomocy

    Potrzebujesz z czymś pomocy? Sprawdź naszą listę poniżej:
    Nie, dziękuję

Już 62 430 użytkowników uczy się języków obcych z Edustation.

Możesz zarejestrować się już dziś i odebrać bonus w postaci 10 monet.

Jeżeli chcesz się dowiedzieć więcej o naszym portalu - kliknij tutaj

Jeszcze nie teraz

lub

Poziom:

Wszystkie

Nie masz konta?

4. Financial Markets: Portfolio Diversification and Supporting Financial Institutions (CAPM Model)


Poziom:

Temat: Społeczeństwo i nauki społeczne

Professor Robert Shiller: Today's lecture is about
portfolio diversification and about supporting financial
institutions, notably mutual funds.
It's actually kind of a crusade of mine--I believe that the
world needs more portfolio diversification.
That might sound to you a little bit odd,
but I think it's absolutely true that the same kind of cause
that Emmett Thompson goes through,
which is to help the poor people of the world,
can be advanced through portfolio diversification--I
seriously mean that. There are a lot of human
hardships that can be solved by diversifying portfolios.
What I'm going to talk about today applies not just to
comfortable wealthy people, but it applies to everyone.
It's really about risk. When there's a bad outcome for
anyone, that's the outcome of some random draw.
When people get into real trouble in their lives,
it's because of a sequence of bad events that push them into
unfortunate positions and, very often, financial risk
management is part of the thing that prevents that from
happening. The first--let me go--I want to
start this lecture with some mathematics.
It's a continuation of the second lecture,
where I talked about the principle of dispersal of risk.
I want now to carry that forward into something a little
bit more focused on the portfolio problem.
I'm going to start this lecture with a discussion of how one
constructs a portfolio and what are the mathematics of it.
That will lead us into the capital asset pricing model,
which is the cornerstone of a lot of thinking in finance.
I'm going to go through this rather quickly because there are
other courses at Yale that will cover this more thoroughly,
notably, John Geanakoplos's Econ 251.
I think we can get the basic points here.
Let's start with the basic idea. I want to just say it in the
simplest possible terms. What is it that--First of all,
a portfolio, let's define that.
A portfolio is the collection of assets that you
have--financial assets, tangible assets--it's your
wealth. The first and fundamental
principle is: you care only about the total
portfolio. You don't want to be someone
like the fisherman who boasts about one big fish that he
caught because it's not--we're talking about livelihoods.
It's all the fish that you caught, so there's nothing to be
proud of if you had one big success.
That's the first very basic principle.
Do you agree with me on that? So, when we say portfolio
management, we mean managing everything that gives you
economic benefit. Now, underlying our theory is
the idea that we measure the outcome of your investment in
your portfolio by the mean of the return on the portfolio and
the variance of the return on the portfolio.
The return, of course, in any given time period is the
percentage increase in the portfolio;
or, it could be a negative number, it could be a decrease.
The principle is that you want the expected value of the return
to be as high as possible given its variance and you want the
variance of the return on the portfolio to be as low as
possible given the return, because high expected return is
a good thing. You could say,
I think my portfolio has an expected return of 12%--that
would be better than if it had an expected return of 10%.
But, on the other hand, you don't want high variance
because that's risk; so, both of those matter.
In fact, different people might make different choices about how
much risk they're willing to bear to get a higher expected
return. But ultimately,
everyone agrees I--that's the premise here,
that for the--if you're comparing two portfolios with
the same variance, then you want the one with the
higher expected return. If you're comparing two
portfolios with the same expected return,
then you want the one with the lower variance.
All right is that clear and--okay.
So let's talk about--why don't I just give it in a very
intuitive term. Suppose we had a lot of
different stocks that we could put into a portfolio,
and suppose they're all independent of each other--that
means there's no correlation. We talked about that in Lecture
2. There's no correlation between
them and that means that the variance--and I want to talk
about equally-weighted portfolio.
So, we're going to have n independent assets;
they could be stocks. Each one has a standard
deviation of return, call that σ.
Let's suppose that all of them are the same--they all have the
same standard deviation. We're going to call r
the expected return of these assets.
Then, we have something called the square root rule,
which says that the standard deviation of the portfolio
equals the standard deviation of one of the assets,
divided by the square root of n.
Can you read this in the back? Am I making that big enough?
Just barely, okay. This is a special case,
though, because I've assumed that the assets are independent
of each other, which isn't usually the case.
It's like an insurance where people imagine they're insuring
people's lives and they think that their deaths are all
independent. I'm transferring this to the
portfolio management problem and you can see it's the same idea.
I've made a very special case that this is the case of an
equally-weighted portfolio. It's a very important point,
if you see the very simple math that I'm showing up here.
The return on the portfolio is r, but the standard
deviation of the portfolio is σ/√(n).
So, the optimal thing to do if you live in a world like this is
to get n as large possible and you can reduce the
standard deviation of the portfolio very much and there's
no cost in terms of expected return.
In this simple world, you'd want to make n 100
or 1,000 or whatever you could. Suppose you could find 10,000
independent assets, then you could drive the
uncertainty about the portfolio practically to 0.
Because the square root of 10,000 is 100,
whatever the standard deviation of the portfolio is,
you would divide it by 100 and it would become really small.
If you can find assets that all have--that are all independent
of each other, you can reduce the variance of
the portfolio very far. That's the basic principle of
portfolio diversification. That's what portfolio managers
are supposed to be doing all the time.
Now, I want to be more general than this and talk about the
real case. In the real world we don't have
the problem that assets are independent.
The different stocks tend to move up and down together.
We don't have the ideal world that I just described,
but to some extent we do, so we want to think about
diversifying in this world.
Now, I want to talk about forming a portfolio where the
assets are not independent of each other, but are correlated
with each other. What I'm going to do now--let's
start out with the case where--now it's going to get a
little bit more complicated if we drop the independence
assumption. I'm going to drop more than the
independence assumption, I'm going to assume that the
assets don't have the same expected return and they don't
have the same expected variance. I'm going to--let's do the
two-asset case.
There's n = 2, but not independent or not
necessarily independent. Asset 1 has expected return
r_1. This is different--I was
assuming a minute ago that they're all the same--it has
standard--this is the expectation of the return of
Asset 1 and r_2 is the expectation of the
return--I'm sorry, σ_1 is the
standard deviation of the return on Asset 1.
We have the same for Asset 2;
it has an expected return of r_2,
it has a standard deviation of return of σ_2.
Those are the inputs into our analysis.
One more thing, I said they're not independent,
so we have to talk about the covariance between the returns.
So, we're going to have the covariance between
r_1 and r_2,
which you can also call σ_12 and those
are the inputs to our analysis. What we want to do now is
compute the mean and variance of the portfolio--or the mean and
standard deviation, since standard deviation is the
square root of the variance--for different combinations of the
portfolios. I'm going to generalize from
our simple story even more by saying that, let's not assume
that we have equally-weighted. We're going to put
x_1 dollars--let's say we have $1 to
invest, we can scale it up and down, it doesn't matter.
Let's say it's $1 and we're going to put
x_1 in asset 1 and that leaves behind
1-x_1 in asset 2,
because we have $1 total. We're not going to restrict
x_1 to be a positive number because,
as you know or you should know, you can hold negative
quantities of assets, that's called shorting them.
You can call your broker and say, I'd like to short stock
number one and what the broker will do is borrow the shares on
your behalf and sell them and then you own negative shares.
So, we're not going to--x_1 can be
anything and x--this is x_2 =
1-x_1, so x_1 +
x_2 = 1.
Now, we just want to compute what is the mean and variance of
the portfolio and that's simple arithmetic, based on what we
talked about before. I'm going to erase this.
The portfolio mean variance will depend on
x_1 in the way that if you put--if you made
x_1 = 1, it would be asset 1 and if you
made x_1 = 0, then it would be the same as
asset 2 returns. But, in between,
if some other number, it'll be some blend of
the--mean and variance of--the portfolio will be some blend of
the mean and variance of the two assets.
The portfolio expected return is going to be given by the
summation i = 1 to n, of x_i*r
_i,. In this case,
since n = 2 that's x_1
r_1 + x_2
r_2, or that's x_1
r_1 + (1 - x_1)
r_2;
that's the expected return on the portfolio.
The variance of the portfolio σ²--this is the
portfolio variance--is σ² =
x_1² σ_1²
+ x_2² σ_2²
+ 2x_1 x_2
σ_12; that's just the formula for the
variance of the portfolio as a function of--Now,
since they have to sum to 1, I can write this as
x_1² σ_1²
+ (1 - x_1)²
σ_2² + 2x_1 (1 -
x_1) σ_12 and so that
together traces out--I can choose any value of
x_1 I want, it can be number from minus
infinity to plus infinity. That shows me then for any
value of x_1, I can compute what r is
and what σ² is and I can then describe the
opportunities I have from investing that depend on these.
Now, one thing to do is to solve the equation for r
and x_1 and I can then recast the variance in
terms of r ; that gives us the variance of
the portfolio as a function of the expected return of the
portfolio. Let me just solve this
for--let's solve x_1 for
r. I've got--this should be x--did I make a
mistake there--so it says that r_1 -
r_2 = x_1
r_1 - r_2,
so x_1 = (r -
r_2)/( r_1 -
r_2) and I can substitute this into this
equation and I get the portfolio variance as a function of the
portfolio expected return r. That's all the basic math
that we need. If I do that,
then I get what's called the frontier for the portfolio.
I have an example on the screen here, but it shows other things.
Let me just--rather than--maybe I'm showing too many things at
once. Let me just draw it.
I'll leave that up for now but we're moving to that.
What we're doing here is the--with two assets,
if I plot the expected annual return r on this axis and
I plot the variance of the portfolio on this axis,
what we have--I'm sorry, the standard deviation of the
portfolio return.
It tends to look--it looks something like this--it's a
hyperbola; there's a minimum variance
portfolio where this σ is as small as possible and
there are many other possible portfolios that lie along this
curve. The curve includes points on
it, which would represent the initial assets.
For example, we might have--this is asset
1--and we might have something here--this could be asset 2.
Depending on where the assets expected returns are and the
assets' standard deviations, we can see that we might be
able to do better than--have a lower variance than either
asset. The equally-weighted case that
I gave a minute ago was one where the two assets had--were
at the same--had the same expected return and the same
variance; but this is quite a bit more
general. So that's the expected return
and efficient portfolio frontier problem.
I wanted to show an example with real data that I computed
and that's what's up on the screen.
The pink line takes two assets, one is stocks and the other is
bonds, actually government bonds.
I computed the efficient portfolio frontier for
various--it's the efficient portfolio frontier using the
formula I just gave you. The pink line here is the
efficient portfolio frontier when we have only stocks and
bonds to invest. You can see the different
points--I've calculated this using data from 1983 until
2006--and I computed all of the inputs to those equations that
we just saw. I computed the average return
on stocks over that time period and I computed the average
return on bonds over that time period.
These are long-term government bonds and I--now these
are--since they're long-term, they have some uncertainty and
variability to them. I computed the
σ_1, σ_2,
r_1, and r_2 for
those and I plugged it into that formula, which we just showed.
That's the curve that I got out. It shows the standard deviation
of the return on the portfolio as a function of the expected
return on the portfolio. I can achieve any
combination--I can achieve any point on that by choosing an
allocation of my portfolio. This point right here is,
on the pink line, is a portfolio 100% bonds.
Over this time period, that portfolio had an expected
return of something like a little over 9% and it had a
standard deviation of a little over 9%.
This is a portfolio, which is 100% stocks,
and that portfolio had a much higher average return or
expected return--13%--but it also had a much higher standard
deviation of return--it was about 16%.
So, you can see that those are the two raw portfolios.
That could be investor only in bonds or an investor only in
stocks, but I also show on here what some other returns are that
are available. The minimum variance portfolio
is down here. That's got the lowest possible
standard deviation of expected return and that's 25% stocks and
75% bonds with this sample period.
I can try other portfolios; this one right here--I'm
pointing to a point on the pink line--that point right there,
50% stocks, 50% bonds. You can see–You can also
go up here, you can go beyond 100% stocks, you can have 150%
stocks in your portfolio. That means you'd have a
leveraged portfolio, you would be borrowing.
If you had $1 to invest you can borrow $.50 and invest in a
$1.50 worth of stocks. That would put you out here;
you would have very much more return, but you'd have more
risk. Borrowing to buy stocks is
going to be risky. You could also pick a point
down here, which is more than 100% bonds--how would you do
that? Well, you could short in the
stock market, you could short $.50 worth of
stocks and buy $1.50 worth of bonds and that would put you
down here. Any one of those things is
possible it's just the simple math that I just showed you.
Do you have any idea what you would like to do,
assuming this? Well if you're an investor,
you don't like variance. So, you probably don't want to
pick any point down here, because you're not getting
anything by picking a point down there because you could have a
better point by just moving it up here.
You'd have a higher expected return with no more variance.
It's getting kind of complicated, isn't it?
We started out with just a simple idea: that you don't want
to put all your eggs in one basket and if you had a lot of
independent stocks you would want to just weight them
equally. But now, you see there are a
lot of possibilities and the outcome of your portfolio choice
can be anything along this line. I'm not going to tell you what
you want to do except to say, you would never pick a point
below the minimum variance portfolio, right?
Because, if you did, then you would always be
dominated. You could always find a
portfolio that had a higher expected return for the same
standard deviation. But beyond that,
if you were confined to just stocks and bonds,
it would be a matter of taste where along this frontier you
would be. You would call it an efficient
portfolio frontier. It would be anywhere from here
to here, depending on how much you're afraid of risk and how
much you want expected return. Now, we can also move to three
assets and, in fact, to any number of assets.
The same formula extends to more assets.
In fact, I have it--suppose we have three assets and we want to
compute the efficient portfolio frontier, the mean and variance
of the portfolio. What I have up there on the
diagram are calculations I made for the efficient portfolio
frontier with three assets. So, now we have n = 3
and in the chart are stocks, bonds, and oil.
Oil is a very important asset, so we want to compute what
that--so now we have lots of inputs.
Let's put the inputs--r_1,
r_2, and r_3 are
the expected returns on the three assets.
Then, we have the standard deviations of the returns of the
three assets and we have the covariance between the returns
on the three assets. There are three of them--
σ_12, σ_13,
and σ_23. That's what we have to know to
compute the efficient portfolio frontier with three assets.
To make this picture, I did that.
I computed the returns on the stocks, bonds,
and oil for every year from 1983 and I computed the average
returns, which I take as the expected
returns, I took the standard deviations, and I took the
covariance. These are all formulas,
I just plugged it into formulas that we did in the second
lecture. What is the portfolio expected
return? The portfolio expected
return--we have to choose three things now:
x_1, x_2,
and x_3. x_1 is the
amount that I put into the first asset, x_2 is
the amount that I put into the second asset,
and x3 is the amount I put into the third asset.
I'm going to constrain them to sum to one.
The return on the portfolio is x_1
r_1 + x_2
r_2 + x_3
r_3. The variance of the portfolio,
σ², is x_1²
σ_1^(2) + x_2²
σ_2² + x_3²
σ_3² -- then we have to the count of
all of the covariance terms -- + 2x_1x
_2 σ_12 +
2x_1x_3 σ_13 +
2x_2x_3 σ_23.
Is that clear enough? It seems like a logical
extension of that formula to three assets and you can easily
see how to extend it to four or more assets,
it's just the logical extension of that.
What I did in this diagram is I computed the efficient portfolio
frontier--now it's the blue line with three assets.
Now, once you have more than three--more than two assets--it
might be possible to get points inside the frontier.
But I'm talking here--this is the actually the frontier--the
best possible portfolio consisting of three assets.
You can see that it dominates the pink line.
When you add another asset, you do better when you have
three assets, you do better than if you just
had two because there's more diversification possible with
three assets than with two. Oil, bonds, and stocks are all
independent--somewhat independent--they're not
perfectly independent, but they're somewhat
independent and, to the extent that they are,
it lowers the variance. You should see that the blue
line is better than the pink line because,
for any expected return, the blue line is to the left of
the pink line, right?
So, for example, at an annual expected return of
12% if I have a portfolio of stocks,
bonds, and oil I can get a standard deviation of something
like 8% on my portfolio. But if I would confine myself
just to stocks and bonds, then I would get a much higher
standard deviation. Are you following this?
The general principle of portfolio management is:
you want to include as many assets as you can.
You want to get it--if you keep adding assets,
you can do better and better on your portfolio standard
deviation. You can see some of the points
I've made along the blue line here.
This is--let's see if I have it. This is a portfolio,
which has all oil and stocks and it has no bonds.
This portfolio, the minimum variance portfolio,
is 9% oil, 27% stocks, and 64% bonds and most of
the--many choices you can make. The first--you see,
the idea here is that in order to manage portfolios what we
want to do is calculate these statistics,
which are the expected returns on the various assets,
the standard deviations of the various assets,
and you've got to know their covariances because that affects
the variance of the portfolio. The more they covary--they move
together--the less they cancel out.
So, the higher the covariance is, generally,
the higher--you can see from here--the higher the
σ² of the portfolio.
Is that clear? There's one more thing that we
can do. I have three assets shown here.
I have stocks, bonds, and oil but I want also
to add one more final asset, we'll call it the riskless
asset, which is the
asset–long-term bonds are somewhat uncertain and variable
because they're long-term. If we have an annual return
that we're looking at, we can find a completely
riskless asset with an annual return--it would be a government
bond that matures in one year. Now, assuming that we trust the
government--I think the U.S. Government has never defaulted
on its debt--we'd take that as a riskless return.
It probably has some risk, but the way we approximate
things in finance, we take the government as
riskless. With the government expected
return, we want to make that expected return as a fourth
asset--we could call it r_4 but I'll
call it r_f--it's a
special asset. So r_f is the
riskless asset.
So, for it, σ_f = 0.
It's like a fourth asset but we're using a special feature of
this asset: that it has no risk. Moreover, the correlation--the
covariance between any of these σ_1f = 0,
etc. It just doesn't have any risk
to it, it has no variability. If we want to add that asset to
the portfolio, what it does is it produces an
efficient portfolio frontier that is now a straight line;
I show that on the diagram. The best possible portfolio
that you can get would be points along this straight line.
That is the final aspect of the efficient portfolio
calculations. Again, I'm not able to give
this as much of a discussion as I would like because I don't
want to spend too much time on this.
In the review sections I'm hopeful that your T.A.'s can
elaborate on this more. There's a very important
principle that finally comes out here, it is that you always want
to reduce the variance of your portfolio as much as you can.
That means that you want to pick, ultimately,
a point on this--this line is tangent to the efficient
portfolio frontier with all the other assets in it.
Tangent means that it has the same slope, it just touches the
efficient portfolio frontier for risky assets at one point,
and the slope of the efficient portfolio frontier,
including the riskless asset, is a straight line that goes
through the tangency point, here.
That is the--I think that's the end of my mathematics.
What I have shown here is how you calculate your portfolio
management. The way you would go about it,
if you're a portfolio manager, is you have to come up with
estimates of the inputs to these formulas--that means the
expected returns, the standard deviations,
and the covariances. You take all the risky assets
and you analyze them first to get their--you have to do a
statistical analysis to get their expected returns,
their variances, and their covariances.
Once you've got them together, then you can compute the
efficient portfolio frontier without the riskless asset.
Then finally, the final step is to find what
is the tangency line that goes through the riskless rate.
It doesn't show it on this chart, it goes through 5% at a
standard deviation of 0, then it touches the risky asset
efficient portfolio frontier at one point, then from there it
goes up above in terms of higher expected returns for the same
variance. That's the theory of efficient
portfolio calculation. There's something that--a
fundamental principle--and this is leading us now to the
institutional topic of this course--is that there's only one
tangency portfolio and that portfolio is called the tangency
portfolio, where a line drawn from the
risk--from the x-axis at the riskless rate is tangent to the
efficient portfolio frontier. The tangency portfolio is the
portfolio that one should hold. The tangency portfolio gives
rise to what's called the mutual fund theorem in finance,
which says that all investors need is a single mutual fund.
Now, I haven't defined mutual fund yet.
A mutual fund is an investment vehicle that allows investors to
hold a portfolio. The theory of mutual funds is:
nobody is supposed to be holding anything other than--the
ideal theory of mutual funds is holding something other than
this tangency portfolio. So, why don't we set up a
company that creates a portfolio like that and investors can buy
into that portfolio. What this--if my analysis is
right--namely, if I've got all of the right
estimates of the expected returns on stocks,
bonds, and oil, and the standard deviations and
covariances--and assuming the interest rate is 5%,
which is what I've assumed here, that this line,
if you go to 0 it hits that 5%. It hits the vertical access at
5%. Then everyone should be holding
the tangency portfolio. What is the tangency portfolio
in this case? It's 12% oil,
36% stocks, and 52% bonds. That's what I got using this
sample period. Some people might disagree with
that, they might not take my estimates.
They might say my sample period was off, but that's what the
theory--using my data for the sample period that I
computed--the expected returns and co-variances says one should
do. The theory says everybody
should be investing in these proportions and this theory
then--it doesn't leave any latitude for individual choice
except that you can choose which mixture of the mutual fund and
the riskless asset you want. Somebody who is very risk
averse could say, I want to hold only the
riskless assets because I just don't like any risk at all.
That person--I should have maybe included that in the
diagram--that person could get 5% return with no risk.
Somebody else might say, well I want to just hold this
point, I want to hold the tangency portfolio.
That's attractive to me because I could then get a bigger
expected return, I could get almost 12% return
per year, and I'd sacrifice--I'd have
some standard deviation of like 8%;
but, if that's what I want, if I have different tastes
about risk, then--and that's what I want--then that's the
optimal thing to do. Other people might say,
well you know, I'm really an adventurer--I
don't care too much about risk--I want the much higher
return. Such a person might pick a
point up here and that would be a portfolio with--a leveraged
portfolio. That would be a portfolio where
you borrowed at the riskless rate and you put more than 100%
of your money into the tangency portfolio.
What you could do is, say, borrow $.50 on your $1 and
put $1.50 into a portfolio, which consisted of 9% oil,
27% stocks, and 64% bonds. Everyone would do that,
no one would ever hold some other portfolio because you can
see that this line is the lowest--it's far--you want to
get to the left as far as possible.
You want to, for any given expected return,
you want to minimize the standard deviation,
so it's the left-most line and that means that everyone will be
holding the same portfolio. I don't find that my analysis
is profound in the final answer, I just took some estimates
using my data and, again, we could--if someone
wanted to argue with us they could argue with my estimates of
the expected returns of the standard deviations and the
covariances, but not with this theory.
This theory is very rigorous. If you agree with my estimates,
then you should do this as an investor, you should hold only
some mixture of this tangency portfolio,
which is 9% oil, 27% stocks, and 64% bonds.
You see what we've got here? I started out with the
equally-weighted--I was talking about stocks--about n
stocks that all have the same variance and are all independent
of each other. But, I've dropped that
assumption and now I'm going on to assuming that they're taking
account of their dependence on each other,
taking account of their different expected returns,
and taking account of their different covariances and
variances; so that's what we've got.
This is a famous framework. This diagram is,
I think, the most famous diagram in all of financial
theory and it's actually the first theoretical diagram.
I did it myself using my data, but it would always look more
or less like this--slightly different positions if people
use different estimates. I actually showed this
diagram--I went to Norway with my colleague--I actually have a
couple more pictures here.
That's my colleague, Ronit Walny,
and I, we're posing in front of the Parliament Building in Oslo.
We went to Norway to discuss the--with the Norwegian
Government--their portfolio. This is a slide that I showed
them. I showed them the slide that I
just showed you, showing the optimal portfolio,
and then I looked at the Norwegian Government's position.
The Norwegian Government has pension fund assets in the
amount of, as of 2006, just under two trillion
Norwegian Kroner; but they also own North Sea Oil.
If you know that, it's kind of divided between
the UK and Norway. Norway has a much smaller
population than the UK and they have a lot of oil up there in
the North Sea. As of then, I calculated the
value of their oil in the North Sea and that's what I got--it's
worth about 3.5 billion Norwegian Kroner.
Do you see the difference? In fact, the assets that the
Norwegian Government owns is about two-thirds oil and
one-third government pension fund assets.
This government pension fund, I guess, in dollars,
is about $200 billion. It's a huge amount of money
that they're managing, but I was trying to convince
them that they should do something to manage their oil
risks because they're way over-invested in oil.
Where are they on the efficient portfolio frontier?
They have 64% oil in their portfolio.
Where does that put them? Well it's not--it's really off
the diagram. The furthest point that I
recorded was 28% oil--that puts them there--so if they--if you
wanted to, where would it be? It would be somewhere over
there off the charts. What the Norwegian Government
is doing wrong is--it's a little bit controversial,
my pointing this out to them. I ended up in the newspaper the
next day for having argued that they are way off on their
investment opportunities because oil is such a volatile thing.
They've got so much of their assets tied up in oil.
I got a good hearing. I went to the Ministry of
Finance and we went to the Norges Bank, which is their
central bank, and I think the answer I got
from them was, yes you're right.
I never got it quite like that--something like that.
There was a conditional agreement: yes,
Norway should manage this oil risk but it's politically
difficult and that's the problem--is that we're not able
to do our optimal management. Maybe there are a number of
structural problems that prevent them from doing that and they
think, maybe, that--I think Norway may
be moving that way, so we'll see in the future.
I went to the Bank of Mexico; I tried to convince the--I met
the president of the Bank of Mexico and tried to tell them
that Mexico is too reliant on oil,
too much oil--they have to get rid of their risk.
I'm going to the Russian Stabilization Fund in--I think
I've got an arrangement to meet with them in Moscow in
March--that would be during the semester.
I'll tell you what reaction I hope I get from the Russians.
Oil is very important to the Russian economy and are they
managing the risk well? I bet not.
I'm going to do a diagram like this for Russia.
The countries that really matter are the ones that--the
Arabian--are the Persian Gulf countries;
I was just talking to people at the World Economic Forum about
that. Some of those countries are
really reliant on oil, so they really have to do--they
really should do a calculation of efficient portfolio
frontiers. Well, one of the lessons of
this course is we have a wonderful theory,
but we don't manage it well, mostly.
And I don't mean to be criticizing foreign countries.
The same criticism applies to the United States as well.
We're in a different position. Where are we on this frontier
regarding oil in the United States?
Well, we don't have much oil relative to the size of our
portfolio. I don't know what percent;
our oil reserves in the U.S. are pretty small,
so we're kind of lying somewhere inside--maybe on this
pink line. So, people in the U.S.
don't have the optimal portfolio either.
I set up a theoretical framework here and I wanted to
give you--I mentioned oil because it seems to make it,
to me, so clear what we're talking about here.
It's talking about not getting tied up in risks and so--I was
talking to someone at the World Economic Forum from a Persian
Gulf country and I said, aren't you worried about
reliance on oil? He said, of course we're
worried on reliance, so much of our GDP and of our
government revenues is oil-related.
We've seen the price of oil, lately, move all over the map.
It went up to $100 recently and it was just as late as late
1990s that it was under $20 and people just don't know where
it's going to go. I think that these countries
are somewhat trying to manage this oil risk but they can't yet
get onto the frontier. That's a sign to me that we're
not there yet and we have a lot more to do in finance.
There's one more equation that I wanted to write down and I'm
going to not--I'm not going to spend a lot of time explaining
this because it's going to take awhile.
This is the equation that relates the expected return on
an asset. It's so called capital asset
pricing model. In the capital asset pricing
model, in finance--this is the most famous model in finance.
It's abbreviated as the CAPM and I'm not going to do it
justice here, I'm sorry, but there are so
many ins and outs of this. You should really take ECON 251
to learn this more. It was--the model divided by
James Tobin here at Yale, was the original--who got the
original precursors, but it was more invented by
William Sharpe, John Lintner,
Harry Markowitz.
Everyone of these, except Lintner I think,
won the Nobel Prize. I think he died too
young--that's one of the misfortunes of living.
Did I say that right? One of the misfortunes of
scholarship, you have to live long enough to get your
accolades. The asset pricing model--and
this is critical--assumes everyone is rational and holds
the tangency portfolio.
That is a wild assumption, but it's fun to make,
because I know pretty well--I know very well--that people
aren't doing this. They have lots of maybe
good--maybe it's not because they're irrational,
it's that they're political or they're constrained by tradition
or laws or regulations, all sorts of things;
but, they're not holding the tangency portfolio.
It's a beautiful theory to assume, to see what would happen
if they did. That would mean that everybody
is holding that same portfolio of risky assets and nobody is
different, they're only different in
how--what proportions they hold the risky--the tangency
portfolio. It implies that the tangency
portfolio has to equal the actual market portfolio and that
means then--it's a very simple implication of the theory.
In my diagram, I said that the tangency
portfolio--I estimated that the tangency portfolio is 9% oil,
27% stocks, and 64% bonds. If we're all doing that,
then that has to be what the outstanding is.
If we're all holding the same portfolio, that has to be the
total, so that would mean that 9% of all wealth is oil,
9% of all--is oil--27% of all wealth is stocks,
and 64% is bonds. If you accept my estimates and
you accept the capital asset pricing model,
that would have to be true. Again, I don't want to make too
much of my estimates because different people would estimate
these things in different ways, but that's the theory.
The theory says that the tangency portfolio equals the
optimal portfolio and that gives us the famous equation--I'm not
going to derive this, but there is the most famous
equation in finance--says--can you read that?
That r_i, the expected return on the
ith asset, is equal to the riskless rate
plus something called the beta for the ith asset times the
expected return on the market minus the riskless rate.
Again, I'm not going to spend much time on this,
but the β of the ith asset is the
regression coefficient when you regress the return on the
ith asset on the return of the market portfolio.
r_m is the expected return on the market
portfolio, which is the portfolio of all assets.
The market portfolio is, if you took all the stocks and
bonds, and oil, and real estate,
anything that's available to invest in, in the whole world,
put them all together in one portfolio.
It's the world portfolio, it's everything and we compute
the expected return on that portfolio, that's
r_m. Also, we need to know how much
individual stocks are correlated with r_m;
we measure that by the regression coefficient.
The β of a stock is how much it reacts to movements in
the market portfolio. If β = 1,
it means that if the market portfolio goes up 10% in value
then this asset also goes up 10% in value.
If β is two, it means that if the market
goes up 10% in value, the stock tends to go up 20% in
value and so on. These are the basic theoretical
structures that you incidentally need for the problem set,
the first problem set. The first problem set--I guess
you've--you can turn in your first problem set here before
you leave because it was due today.
The second problem set is about this model.
I realize I've given you some difficult mathematics,
but--it's not that difficult actually--but I kind of went
through it quickly. So, we are setting up our--you
have already gotten email and you've talked about setting up
your review sessions--so I have a few more minutes here.
What I want to do, I want to talk about Jeremy
Siegel's book and the equity premium puzzle.
Underlying this analysis, we have estimates of the
expected returns on assets, notably, the expected returns
on stocks and bonds.
Jeremy Siegel, in his book,
which is assigned for this course, is really emphasizing
this capital asset pricing model,
emphasizing the kind of efficient portfolio frontier
calculations that I've done. What Siegel emphasized--the
book is really about this--he talks about what is the expected
return of stocks and what is the expected return of bonds and so
on. We're going to call asset one
stocks in the U.S. and we're going to call asset
two bonds. He estimates,
for his purposes, and he shows you calculations
of the efficient portfolio frontier.
I want to just talk a little bit about his estimate.
He has data for a very long time period, 1802 to 2006,
for the U.S.
Over that very long time interval, the expected return
that we got for stocks was 6.8% a year in real terms,
this is real inflation corrected;
whereas, for bonds, it was, over this whole time
period, 2.8% a year, real.
Then he also computes σ_1 and
σ_2 and σ_12 but I'm not
going to talk about that right now.
Then he computes the efficient portfolio frontier.
Now, he's using a much longer sample than I did,
so he's not going to get this tangency portfolio that I did.
The thing that is very interesting that he finds is the
difference, 4%, between the historical real
return on stocks and the historical real return on bonds.
This is called the equity premium.
Actually, I should take that back, this is really
r_f--he shows all three.
r_f that I'm reporting is the riskless rate.
There's also--if you look on Table One in Chapter One,
it shows r_1 stocks,
r_2 long-term bonds, and these are short-term
that I'm recording here. The equity premium is the--this
short-term 2.8% is the riskless return, historically,
for a period of almost 200 years.
This is the return on stocks for a period of almost 200
years. Stocks have paid 4% more a year
over this incredibly long time period than short-term bonds.
Also, they've paid much more than long-term--well it's not so
different. I don't have the data in front
of me, so let's emphasize the difference between
r_1 and r_f.
It surprises many people that stocks have paid such an
enormous premium over the return on short-term debt.
The theme of Siegel's book is, can we believe this?
I mean, do you really--you might wonder,
aren't people missing something if the excess return is so high
of stocks over short-term bonds? Why would anyone not just hold
a lot of--a really large number of stocks?
That's the theme of his book and his book is at--his
conclusion is that he largely believes that this is true,
that the returns that we have seen in the U.S.
in the stock market have exceeded those of other assets
by quite a substantial margin. That means--his calculations
are very different than the ones I have because he has a much
longer sample period. I was using only from 1983 to
the present. For him, the optimal portfolio
should be very heavily into stocks.
Now, this is a controversial view, but that is the view that
he advances in the book and I think it's a very interesting
analysis. So, what it means then is that
the optimal portfolio should not be the one I show there,
but should be one that's very heavily into stocks.
This is--I'm showing here U.S. data, but Siegel also argues in
the latest edition that the equity premium is also high for
advanced countries over the whole world.
If you look at his book, again in the first chapter,
he gives a list of countries--it's based on an
analysis that some others--that Professors Dimson,
Marsh, and Stanton used in their 2002 book.
They show the expected return on stocks versus bonds or
short-term debt for a whole range of countries.
In every one of these countries, since 1901,
there has been a very high equity premium.
I'll let you read Siegel and his discussion of this
possibility, but I think that--what I want to get now is
not necessarily any agreement on whether you believe that there's
such a high excess return for stocks.
but I just want you to understand the basic framework.
The first problem set asked you to manipulate the model that I
just presented--the model of how you form portfolios and the
model of the capital asset pricing model.
I have one final question, just about the mutual fund
industry. The mutual fund industry is
supposedly, and according to theory, doing this for you.
The ideal thing would be that the mutual fund does these
calculations and it puts it all together for you.
At least in some approximate sense that's what they are
doing. I asked you in the final
question to just get on a couple of websites, The Federal Reserve
and the ICI, which is a mutual industry
website, and write a little bit, a couple paragraphs about what
this industry is really achieving or how it's trending.
Next Wednesday–well, there are three lectures this
week, Wednesday will be about the insurance industry and I'll
see you in two days then.
Mobile Analytics