1. Po raz pierwszy odwiedzasz EDU. LEARN

    Odwiedzasz EDU.LEARN

    Najlepszym sposobem na naukę języka jest jego używanie. W EDU.LEARN znajdziesz interesujące teksty i videa, które dadzą Ci taką właśnie możliwość. Nie przejmuj się - nasze filmiki mają napisy, dzięki którym lepiej je zrozumiesz. Dodatkowo, po kliknięciu na każde słówko, otrzymasz jego tłumaczenie oraz prawidłową wymowę.

    Nie, dziękuję
  2. Mini lekcje

    Podczas nauki języka bardzo ważny jest kontekst. Zdjęcia, przykłady użycia, dialogi, nagrania dźwiękowe - wszystko to pomaga Ci zrozumieć i zapamiętać nowe słowa i wyrażenia. Dlatego stworzyliśmy Mini lekcje. Są to krótkie lekcje, zawierające kontekstowe slajdy, które zwiększą efektywność Twojej nauki. Są cztery typy Mini lekcji - Gramatyka, Dialogi, Słówka i Obrazki.

    Dalej
  3. Wideo

    Ćwicz język obcy oglądając ciekawe filmiki. Wybierz temat, który Cię interesuje oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknij na filmik. Nie martw się, obok każdego z nich są napisy. A może wcale nie będą Ci one potrzebne? Spróbuj!

    Dalej
  4. Teksty

    Czytaj ciekawe artykuły, z których nauczysz się nowych słówek i dowiesz więcej o rzeczach, które Cię interesują. Podobnie jak z filmikami, możesz wybrać temat oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknąć na wybrany artykuł. Nasz interaktywny słownik pomoże Ci zrozumieć nawet trudne teksty, a kontekst ułatwi zapamiętanie słówek. Dodatkowo, każdy artykuł może być przeczytany na głos przez wirtualnego lektora, dzięki czemu ćwiczysz słuchanie i wymowę!

    Dalej
  5. Słowa

    Tutaj możesz znaleźć swoją listę "Moje słówka", czyli funkcję wyszukiwania słówek - a wkrótce także słownik tematyczny. Do listy "Moje słówka" możesz dodawać słowa z sekcji Videa i Teksty. Każde z słówek dodanych do listy możesz powtórzyć później w jednym z naszych ćwiczeń. Dodatkowo, zawsze możesz iść do swojej listy i sprawdzić znaczenie, wymowę oraz użycie słówka w zdaniu. Użyj naszej wyszukiwarki słówek w części "Słownictwo", aby znaleźć słowa w naszej bazie.

    Dalej
  6. Lista tekstów

    Ta lista tekstów pojawia się po kliknięciu na "Teksty". Wybierz poziom trudności oraz temat, a następnie artykuł, który Cię interesuje. Kiedy już zostaniesz do niego przekierowany, kliknij na "Play", jeśli chcesz, aby został on odczytany przez wirtualnego lektora. W ten sposób ćwiczysz umiejętność słuchania. Niektóre z tekstów są szczególnie interesujące - mają one odznakę w prawym górnym rogu. Koniecznie je przeczytaj!

    Dalej
  7. Lista Video

    Ta lista filmików pojawia się po kliknięciu na "Video". Podobnie jak w przypadku Tekstów, najpierw wybierz temat, który Cię interesuje oraz poziom trudności, a następnie kliknij na wybrane video. Te z odznaką w prawym górnym rogu są szczególnie interesujące - nie przegap ich!

    Dalej
  8. Dziękujemy za skorzystanie z przewodnika!

    Teraz już znasz wszystkie funkcje EDU.LEARN! Przygotowaliśmy do Ciebie wiele artykułów, filmików oraz mini lekcji - na pewno znajdziesz coś, co Cię zainteresuje!

    Teraz zapraszamy Cię do zarejestrowania się i odkrycia wszystkich możliwości portalu.

    Dziękuję, wrócę później
  9. Lista Pomocy

    Potrzebujesz z czymś pomocy? Sprawdź naszą listę poniżej:
    Nie, dziękuję

Już 62 355 użytkowników uczy się języków obcych z Edustation.

Możesz zarejestrować się już dziś i odebrać bonus w postaci 10 monet.

Jeżeli chcesz się dowiedzieć więcej o naszym portalu - kliknij tutaj

Jeszcze nie teraz

lub

Poziom:

Wszystkie

Nie masz konta?

Dan Ariely asks, Are we in control of our own decisions?


Poziom:

Temat: Społeczeństwo i nauki społeczne

I'll tell you a little bit about irrational behavior.
Not yours, of course. Other people's.
(Laughter)
So after being at MIT for a few years,
I realized that writing academic papers is not that exciting.
You know, I don't know how many of those you read.
But it's not fun to read and often not fun to write.
Even worse to write.
So I decided to try and write something more fun.
And I came up with an idea that I will write a cookbook.
And the title for my cookbook was going to be
"Dining Without Crumbs: The Art of Eating Over the Sink."
(Laughter)
And it was going to be a look at life through the kitchen.
And I was quite excited about this. I was going to talk
a little bit about research, a little bit about the kitchen.
You know, we do so much in the kitchen I thought this would be interesting.
And I wrote a couple of chapters.
And I took it to MIT press and they said,
"Cute. But not for us. Go and find somebody else."
I tried other people and everybody said the same thing,
"Cute. Not for us."
Until somebody said,
"Look, if you're serious about this,
you first have to write a book about your research. You have to publish something.
And then you'll get the opportunity to write something else.
If you really want to do it you have to do it."
So I said, "You know, I really don't want to write about my research.
I do this all day long. I want to write something else.
Something a bit more free, less constrained."
And this person was very forceful and said,
"Look. That's the only way you'll ever do it."
So I said, "Okay, if I have to do it -- "
I had a sabbatical. I said, "I'll write about my research
if there is no other way. And then I'll get to do my cookbook."
So I wrote a book on my research.
And it turned out to be quite fun. In two ways.
First of all I enjoyed writing.
But the more interesting thing was that
I started learning from people.
It's a fantastic time to write.
Because there is so much feedback you can get from people.
People write me about their personal experience,
and about their examples, and what they disagree,
and nuances.
And even being here. I mean the last few days,
I've known really heights of obsessive behavior
I never thought about.
(Laughter)
Which I think is just fascinating.
I will tell you a little bit about irrational behavior.
And I want to start by giving you some examples of visual illusion
as a metaphor for rationality.
So think about these two tables.
And you must have seen this illusion.
If I asked you what's longer, the vertical line on the table on the left,
or the horizontal line on the table on the right?
Which one seems longer?
Can anybody see anything but the left one being longer?
No, right? It's impossible.
But the nice thing about visual illusion is we can easily demonstrate mistakes.
So I can put some lines on. It doesn't help.
I can animate the lines.
And to the extent you believe I didn't shrink the lines,
which I didn't, I've proven to you that your eyes were deceiving you.
Now, the interesting thing about this
is when I take the lines away,
it's as if you haven't learned anything in the last minute.
(Laughter)
You can't look at this and say, "Okay now I see reality as it is."
Right? It's impossible to overcome this
sense that this is indeed longer.
Our intuition is really fooling us in a repeatable, predictable, consistent way.
And there is almost nothing we can do about it.
Aside from taking a ruler and starting to measure it.
Here is another one. This is one of my favorite illusions.
What do you see the color that top arrow is pointing to?
Brown. Thank you.
The bottom one? Yellow.
Turns out they're identical.
Can anybody see them as identical?
Very very hard.
I can cover the rest of the cube up.
and if I cover the rest of the cube you can see that they are identical.
And if you don't believe me you can get the slide later
and do some arts and crafts and see that they're identical.
But again it's the same story
that if we take the background away,
the illusion comes back. Right.
There is no way for us not to see this illusion.
I guess maybe if you're colorblind I don't think you can see that.
I want you to think about illusion as a metaphor.
Vision is one of the best things we do.
We have a huge part of our brain dedicated to vision.
Bigger than dedicated to anything else.
We do more vision more hours of the day than we do anything else.
And we are evolutionarily designed to do vision.
And if we have these predictable repeatable mistakes in vision,
which we're so good at,
what's the chance that we don't make even more mistakes
in something we're not as good at.
For example, financial decision making.
(Laughter)
Something we don't have an evolutionary reason to do.
We don't have a specialized part of the brain,
and we don't do that many hours of the day.
And the argument is in those cases
it might be the issue that we actually make many more mistakes.
And worse, not have an easy way to see them.
Because in visual illusions we can easily demonstrate the mistakes.
In cognitive illusion it's much, much harder
to demonstrate to people the mistakes.
So I want to show you some cognitive illusions,
or decision making illusions, in the same way.
And this is one of my favorite plots in social sciences.
It's from a paper by Johnson and Goldstein.
And it basically shows
the percentage of people who indicated
they would be interested in giving their organs to donation.
And these are different countries in Europe. And you basically
see two types of countries.
Countries on the right that seem to be giving a lot.
And countries on the left that seem to giving very little,
or much less.
The question is, Why? Why do some countries give a lot
and some countries give a little?
When you ask people this question,
they usually think that it has to be something about culture.
Right? How much do you care about people?
Giving your organs to somebody else
is probably about how much you care about society, how linked you are.
Or maybe it is about religion.
But if you look at this plot
you can see that countries that we think about as very similar
actually exhibit very different behavior.
For example, Sweden is all the way on the right.
And Denmark that we think is culturally very similar
is all the way on the left.
Germany is on the left. And Austria is on the right.
The Netherlands is on the left. And Belgium is on the right.
And finally, depending on your particular version
of European similarity,
you can think about the U.K and France as either similar culturally or not.
But it turns out that from organ donation they are very different.
By the way, the Netherlands is an interesting story.
You see the Netherlands is kind of the biggest of the small group.
Turns out that they got to 28 percent
after mailing every household in the country a letter
begging people to join this organ donation program.
You know the expression, "Begging only gets you so far."
It's 28 percent in organ donation.
(Laughter)
But whatever the countries on the right are doing
they are doing a much better job than begging.
So what are they doing?
Turns out the secret has to do with a form at the DMV.
And here is the story.
The countries on the left have form at the DMV
that looks something like this.
Check the box below if you want to participate
in the organ donor program.
And what happens?
People don't check. And they don't join.
The countries on the right, the ones that give a lot,
have a slightly different form.
It says check the box below if you don't want to participate.
Interestingly enough, when people get this,
they again don't check. But now they join.
(Laughter)
Now think about what this means.
We wake up in the morning and we feel we make decisions.
We wake up in the morning and we open the closet.
And we feel that we decide what to wear.
And we open the refrigerator. And we feel that we decide what to eat.
What this is actually saying is that
much of these decisions are not residing within us.
They are residing in the person who is designing that form.
When you walk into the DMV,
the person who designed the form will have a huge influence
on what you'll end up doing.
Now it's also very hard to intuit these results. Think about it for yourself.
How many of you believe
that if you went to renew your license tomorrow,
and you went to the DMV,
and you would encounter one of these forms,
that it would actually change your own behavior?
Very, very hard to think that you will influence us.
We can say, "Oh, these funny Europeans. Of course it would influence them."
But when it comes to us
we have such a feeling that we are at the drivers seat,
we have such a feeling that we are in control,
and we are making the decision,
that it's very hard to even accept
the idea that we actually have
an illusion of making a decision, rather than an actual decision.
Now, you might say,
"These are decisions we don't care about."
In fact, by definition, these are decisions
about something that will happen to us after we die.
How could we care about something less
than something that happens after we die?
So a standard economist, someone who believes in rationality,
would say, "You know what? The cost of lifting the pencil
and marking a V is higher than the possible
benefit of the decision."
So that's why we get this effect.
But, in fact, it's not because it's easy.
It's not because it's trivial. It's not because we don't care.
It's the opposite. It's because we care.
It's difficult and it's complex.
And it's so complex that we don't know what to do.
And because we have no idea what to do
we just pick whatever it was that was chosen for us.
I'll give you one more example for this.
This is from a paper by Redelmeier and Schaefer.
And they said, "Well, this effect also happens to experts,
people who are well paid, experts in their decisions,
do it a lot."
And they basically took a group of physicians.
And they presented to them a case study of a patient.
Here is a patient. He is a 67 year old farmer.
He's been suffering from a right hip pain for a while.
And then they said to the physician,
"You decided a few weeks ago
that nothing is working for this patient.
All these medications. Nothing seems to be working.
So you refer the patient to hip replacement therapy.
Hip replacement. Okay?"
So the patient is on a path to have his hip replaced.
And then they said to half the physicians, they said,
"Yesterday you reviewed the patient's case
and you realized that you forgot to try one medication.
You did not try ibuprofen.
What do you do? Do you pull the patient back and try ibuprofen?
Or do you let them go and have hip replacement?"
Well the good news is that most physicians in this case
decided to pull the patient and try the ibuprofen.
Very good for the physicians.
The other group of the physicians, they said,
"Yesterday when you reviewed the case
you discovered there were two medications you didn't try out yet,
ibuprofen and piroxicam."
And they said, "You have two medications you didn't try out yet. What do you do?
You let them go. Or you pull them back.
And if you pull them back do you try ibuprofen or piroxicam? Which one?"
Now think of it. This decision
makes it as easy to let the patient continue with hip replacement.
But pulling them back, all of the sudden becomes more complex.
There is one more decision.
What happens now?
Majority of the physicians now choose to let the patient go
to hip replacement.
I hope this worries you, by the way --
(Laughter)
when you go to see your physician.
The thing is is that no physician would ever say,
"Piroxicam, ibuprofen, hip replacement.
Let's go for hip replacement."
But the moment you set this as the default
it has a huge power over whatever people end up doing.
I'll give you a couple of more examples on irrational decision making.
Imagine I give you a choice.
Do you want to go for a weekend to Rome?
All expenses paid,
hotel, transportation, food, breakfast,
a continental breakfast, everything.
Or a weekend in Paris?
Now, a weekend in Paris, a weekend in Rome, these are different things.
They have different food, different culture, different art.
Now imagine I added a choice to the set
that nobody wanted.
Imagine I said, "A weekend in Rome,
a weekend in Paris, or having your car stolen?"
(Laughter)
It's a funny idea. Because why would having your car stolen,
in this set, influence anything?
(Laughter)
But what if the option to have your car stolen
was not exactly like this.
What if it was a trip to Rome, all expenses paid,
transportation, breakfast.
But doesn't include coffee in the morning.
If you want coffee you have to pay for it yourself. It's two euros 50.
Now in some ways,
given that you can have Rome with coffee,
why would you possibly want Rome without coffee?
It's like having your car stolen. It's an inferior option.
But guess what happened. The moment you add Rome without coffee,
Rome with coffee becomes more popular. And people choose it.
The fact that you have Rome without coffee
makes Rome with coffee look superior.
And not just to Rome without coffee, even superior to Paris.
(Laughter)
Here are two examples of this principle.
This was an ad from The Economist a few years ago
that gave us three choices.
An online subscription for 59 dollars.
A print subscription for 125.
Or you could get both for 125.
(Laughter)
Now I looked at this and I called up The Economist.
And I tried to figure out what were they thinking.
And they passed me from one person to another to another.
Until eventually I got to a person who was in charge of the website.
And I called them up. And they went to check what was going on.
The next thing I know, the ad is gone. And no explanation.
So I decided to do the experiment
that I would have loved The Economist to do with me.
I took this and I gave it to 100 MIT students.
I said, "What would you choose?"
These are the market share. Most people wanted the combo deal.
Thankfully nobody wanted the dominated option.
That means our students can read.
(Laughter)
But now if you have an option that nobody wants
you can take it off. Right?
So I printed another version of this.
Where I eliminated the middle option.
I gave it to another 100 students. Here is what happens.
Now the most popular option became the least popular.
And the least popular became the most popular.
What was happening was the option that was useless,
in the middle, was useless in the sense that nobody wanted it.
But it wasn't useless in the sense that it helped people figure out
what they wanted.
In fact, relative to the option in the middle,
which was get only the print for 125,
the print and web for 125 looked like a fantastic deal.
And as a consequence, people chose it.
The general idea here, by the way,
is that we actually don't know our preferences that well.
And because we don't know our preferences that well
we're susceptible to all of these influences from the external forces.
The defaults, the particular options that are presented to us. And so on.
One more example of this.
People believe that when we deal with physical attraction,
we see somebody, and we know immediately whether we like them or not.
Attracted or not.
Which is why we have these four-minute dates.
So I decided to do this experiment with people.
I'll show you graphic images of people -- not real people.
The experiment was with people.
I showed some people a picture of Tom, and a picture of Jerry.
I said "Who do you want to date? Tom or Jerry?"
But for half the people I added an ugly version of Jerry.
I took Photoshop and I made Jerry slightly less attractive.
(Laughter)
The other people, I added an ugly version of Tom.
And the question was, will ugly Jerry and ugly Tom
help their respective, more attractive brothers?
The answer was absolutely yes.
When ugly Jerry was around, Jerry was popular.
When ugly Tom was around, Tom was popular.
(Laughter)
This of course has two very clear implications
for life in general.
If you ever go bar hopping who do you want to take with you?
(Laughter)
You want a slightly uglier version of yourself.
(Laughter)
Similar. Similar ... but slightly uglier.
(Laughter)
The second point, or course, is that
if somebody else invites you, you know how they think about you.
(Laughter)
Now you're getting it.
What is the general point?
The general point is that when we think about economics we have
this beautiful view of human nature.
"What a piece of work is man! How noble in reason!"
We have this view of ourselves, of others.
The behavioral economics perspective
is slightly less generous to people.
In fact in medical terms, that's our view.
(Laughter)
But there is a silver lining.
The silver lining is, I think,
kind of the reason that behavioral economics is interesting and exciting.
Are we Superman? Or are we Homer Simpson?
When it comes to building the physical world,
we kind of understand our limitations.
We build steps. And we build these things
that not everybody can use obviously.
(Laughter)
We understand our limitations.
And we build around it.
But for some reason when it comes to the mental world,
when we design things like healthcare and retirement and stockmarkets,
we somehow forget the idea that we are limited.
I think that if we understood our cognitive limitations
in the same way that we understand our physical limitations,
even though they don't stare us in the face in the same way,
we could design a better world.
And that, I think, is the hope of this thing.
Thank you very much.
(Applause)
Mobile Analytics